Defining characteristics of
political economy analysis
'Political economy analysis is concerned with the
interaction of political and economic processes within a society: the
distribution of power and wealth between different groups and individuals, and the
processes that create, sustain and transform these relationships over time.'
As the name suggests, political economy is
concerned with how political forces influence the economy and
economic outcomes. However, the interactions run both ways and political
economy is interested in both. Thus, it is economic activity that generates the
resources that are required to sustain political activity, for example,
election campaign expenses. Moreover, whilst policy might lead to a certain
economic activity prospering, this success in itself can generate a political
constituency with an interest in maintaining the economic activity, because a
sizeable number of people now benefit from it.
As was noted above, the distribution of benefits from economic activity
tends to be a neglected aspect of much pure economic analysis. However, within
political economy analysis it takes centre stage. Political economists are very
interested in who gains and who loses from a
particular policy. This is likely to provide important clues as to which groups
or individuals support the continuation of the policy, as well as to which
groups might be drawn into a coalition seeking to change it.
Using economic tools to examine political
phenomena
Another characteristic of political economy analysis is that it uses
economic tools to examine political phenomena. As in economics, a
characteristic of political economy analysis is the assumption that individual
(political) agents are both self-seeking and rational.
Economics examines how rational individuals use the resources at their disposal
(capital, labour, land etc) to maximise some utility function (for example,
maximising profits, income or consumption) by producing goods and services and
participating in markets. In a similar vein, political economy examines how
such individuals maximise their utility by participating in political activity.
Again they have capital and labour (time) at their disposal and they can use
these to influence political processes so as to generate policy outcomes that
benefit them (most notably, by generating rents for them).
DFID (2009) thus sees political behaviour as being shaped by:
- Interests:
those with the ability to influence policy do so in such a way as to
further their own economic and/or political interests. Those outside of
government may be particularly concerned with economic outcomes. Those
inside government might have their own private economic interests, as
earlier discussions highlighted. However, they also have political
interests, most obviously to retain their positions of power.
- Ideas:
ideology remains an important driver of policy, alongside direct economic
or political interests. Where individuals are constrained by bounded
rationality, such that they cannot reliably assess all the possible outcomes
from all the different (policy or voting) choices open to them, ideology
gives them a (more or less accurate) guide as to what they should do in
order to remain consistent with their basic beliefs and values in life.
Incorporating ideas or ideology into political economy models also allows
for the fact that some political action is motivated by factors other than
pure self-interest. Some people do genuinely enter politics because they
want to make the world a better place, although whether that remains their
guiding motivation throughout their political career is another question!
- Institutions:
as explained by North (1990), institutions are the formal or informal
'rules of the game' that structure human behaviour. Generally, there are
formal political rules, including a constitution, that define matters such
as how leaders are chosen and how a new policy can be introduced. In
practice, informal norms and ways of doing things might be as influential
in shaping actual outcomes. All these rules help to structure the
incentives facing political actors.
Levels and choices
DFID (2009) describe tools of political economy analysis that are
relevant to three levels:
- Macro-level
or country analysis: at this level one can
understand how the big decisions, for example, with respect to the
selection of political leaders or the allocation of budgets, are made. One
would expect the most powerful interest groups – whether they be
industrial, ethnic or otherwise – to be visible at this level. Macro
analysis might also consider how the highest level political institutions
function: what are the rules of the game facing top political players? One
might also expect a country’s history to shape prevailing ideologies and
ideas about how things should work and why.
- Sector-level
analysis: this examines in more depth the forces
shaping policy formation and decision-making at the level of an individual
sector or industry. The more important and prominent the sector is within
the national economy, the greater one would expect the influence of
national level forces to be over decision-making within the sector.
However, the possibilities facing all sectors are to some extent
constrained by the broader macro context, including budget, macro-economic
policy etc. Meanwhile, one would expect actors who do not feature in
high-level political debates and events nevertheless to exert influence
over outcomes in their particular sector. Moreover, sectoral and local
rules will be critical to outcomes and hence fiercely contested by the
relevant players.
- Problem-driven
analysis: this is a highly practical approach that
starts from a particular problem that needs solving and proceeds to
examine all the forces (actors and interests, ideas, institutions) that
have a bearing on it. According to DFID (2009) the World Bank developed
this approach to understand situations where policy reforms that were
desirable from a growth or poverty reduction perspective seemed to be
continually blocked.