The twin secular stagnations hypothesis (TSSH, first postulated on this blog)
that combines supply-side (technological cyclicality) and demand-side (demographic
cyclicality) arguments for why the world economy may have settled on a lower
growth trajectory than the one prevailing before 2007 has been a recurrent
feature of a number of my posts on this blog, and has entered several of my
policy and academic research papers. Throughout my usual discourse on the
subject, I have persistently argued that the TSSH accommodates the view that
the Global Financial Crisis and the associated Great Recession and the Euro
Area Sovereign Crisis of 2007-2014 have significantly accelerated the onset of
the TSSH. In other words, TSSH is not a displacement of the arguments that
attribute current economic dynamics (slow productivity growth, slower growth in
the real economy, reallocation of returns from labour and human capital to
technological capital and, more significantly, the financial capital) to the
aftermath of the structural crises we experienced in the recent past. The two
sets of arguments are, in my view, somewhat complementary.
The paper starts with the - relatively common in the literature - superficial
(in my opinion) dichotomy between the secular stagnation hypothesis and the
"alternative explanation" of the slowdown in the economy, namely
"that large, temporary downturns can themselves permanently damage an
economy’s productive capacity." The latter is the so-called 'hysteresis
hypothesis', "according to which changes in current aggregate demand can
have a significant effect on future aggregate supply" which dates back to
the 1980s. The superficiality of this dichotomy relates to the causal chains
involved, and to the impact of the two hypotheses.
However, as the authors note, correctly: "While the two sets of
explanations may be observationally similar, they have very different normative
implications. If exogenous structural factors drive slow growth,
countercyclical policy may be unable to resist or reverse this trend. In
contrast, if temporary downturns themselves lead to persistently or permanently
slower growth, then countercyclical policy, by limiting the severity of
downturns, may have a role to play to avert such adverse developments."
The authors develop a model in which countercyclical monetary policy can
"moderate" the impact of the sudden, but temporary large downturns,
i.e. in the presence of hysteresis. How does this work?
The authors first describe the source of the deep adverse shock capable of
shifting the economy toward long-term lower growth rates: "in our model,
hysteresis can arise because workers lose human capital whilst unemployed and
unskilled workers are costly to retrain". This is not new and goes back to
the 1990s work on hysteresis. The problem is explaining why exactly such deep
depreciation takes place. Long unemployment spells do reduce human capital
stock for workers, but long unemployment spells are feature of less skilled
workforce, so there is less human capital to depreciate there in the first
place. Retraining low skilled workers is not more expensive than retraining
higher skilled workers. In fact, low skilled workers seek low skilled jobs and
these require only basic training. It is quite possible that low skilled
workers losing their jobs today are of certain demographic (e.g. older workers)
that reduces the effectiveness of retraining programs, but that is the TSSH domain,
not the hysteresis domain.
But, back to the authors: "... large adverse fundamental shocks can cause
recessions whose legacy is persistent or permanent unemployment...
Accommodative policy early in a recession can prevent hysteresis from taking
root and enable swift a recovery. In contrast, delayed monetary policy
interventions may be powerless to bring the economy back to full
employment."
"As in Pissarides (1992), these features [of long unemployment-induced
loss of human capital, sticky wages that prevent wages from falling
significantly during the downturns, costly search for new jobs, and costly
retraining of workers] generate multiple steady states. One steady state is a
high pressure economy: job finding rates are high, unemployment is low and
job-seekers are highly skilled. While tight labor markets - by improving
workers’ outside options - cause wages to be high, firms still find job
creation attractive, as higher wages are offset by low average training costs
when job-seekers are mostly highly skilled." Note: the same holds when
highly skilled workers labour productivity rises to outpace sticky wages, so
one needs to also account for the reasons why labour productivity slacks or
does not keep up with wages growth during the downturn, especially when the
downturn results in selective layoffs of workers who are less productive ahead
of those more productive. Hysteresis hypothesis alone is not enough to do that.
We need fundamental reasons for structural changes in labour productivity that
go beyond simple depreciation of human capital (or, put differently, we need
something similar to the TSSH).
"The economy, however, can also be trapped in a low pressure steady state.
In this steady state, job finding rates are low, unemployment is high, and many
job-seekers are unskilled as long unemployment spells have eroded their human
capital. Slack labor markets lower the outside options of workers and drive
wages down, but hiring is still limited as firms find it costly to retrain
these workers." Once again, I am not entirely convinced we are facing
higher costs of retraining low skilled workers (as argued above), and I am not
entirely convinced we are seeing the problem arising amongst the low skilled
workers to begin with. Post-2008 recovery has been associated with more jobs
creation in lower skilled categories of jobs, e.g. hospitality sector,
restaurants, bars, other basic services. These are low skilled jobs which
require minimal training. And, yet, we are seeing continued trend toward lower
labour force participation rates. Something is missing in the argument that
hysteresis is triggered by cost of retraining workers.
Back to the paper: "Importantly, the transition to an unemployment trap
following a large severe shock can be avoided. If monetary policy commits to
temporarily higher inflation after the liquidity trap has ended, it can
mitigate both the initial rise in unemployment, and its persistent (or
permanent)
negative consequences. Monetary policy, however, is only effective if it is
implemented early in the downturn, before the recession has left substantial
scars... [otherwise] ...fiscal policy, in the form of hiring or training
subsidies, is necessary to engineer a swift recovery."
The paper tests the model in the empirical setting. And the results seem to be
plausible: "allowing for a realistic degree of skill depreciation and
training costs... is sufficient to generate multiple steady states.... this
multiplicity is essential in explaining why the unemployment rate in the U.S.
took 7 years to return to its pre-crisis level. In contrast, the standard
search model without skill depreciation and/or training costs predicts that the
U.S. economy should have fully recovered by 2011. ...the model indicates that
had monetary policy been less accommodative or timely during the crisis,
leading to a peak unemployment rate higher than 11 percent, the economy might
have been permanently scarred and stuck in an unemployment trap. Furthermore,
our model suggests that the persistently high proportion of long-term
unemployed in the European periphery countries may reflect a lack of timely
monetary accommodation by the European Central Bank."
Fraction of Long-term unemployed (>27 weeks) in select countries.
The figure plots five quarter moving averages of quarterly data.
The dashed-line indicates the timing of Draghi’s “whatever it takes” speech.
Source: Eurostat and FRED.
This seems quite plausible, even though it does not explain why eventual
'retraining' of low skilled workers is still not triggering substantial
increases in labour productivity growth rates in Europe and the U.S.
One interesting extension presented in the paper is that of segmented labour
markets, or the markets where "employers might be able to discern whether
a worker requires training or not based on observable characteristics - in particular,
their duration of unemployment... [so that, if] skilled and unskilled workers
searched in separate markets, the economy would still be characterized by
hysteresis, but it would take a different form. There are two possibilities to
consider. [If] ... the firm’s share of the surplus from hiring an unskilled
worker, net of training costs, is large enough to compensate firms for posting
vacancies in the unskilled labor market, ...after a temporary recession which
increases the fraction of unskilled job-seekers, it can take a long time for
these workers to be reabsorbed into employment. Firms prefer to post vacancies
in the market for skilled job-seekers rather than the market for unskilled
job-seekers in order to avoid paying a training cost. With fewer vacancies
posted for them, unskilled job-seekers face a lower job-finding rate and thus,
the outflow from the pool of unskilled job-seekers is low. In contrast, the
skilled unemployment rate recovers rapidly - in fact, faster than in the
baseline model with a single labor market... [Alternatively], the segmented
labor markets economy could experience permanent stagnation, rather than a slow
recovery, [if] unskilled workers are unemployable, since firms are unwilling to
pay the cost of hiring and training these workers. Thus unskilled workers
effectively drop out of the labor force."
We do observe some of the elements of both such regimes in the advanced
economies today, with simultaneous increasing jobs creation drift toward
lower-skilled, slack in supply of skills as younger, educated workers are
forced to compete for lower skilled jobs, and a dropout rate acceleration for
labour force participation. Which suggests that demographics (the TSSH
component, not hysteresis component) is at play at least in part in the
equation.
In summary, a very interesting paper that, in my opinion, adds to the TSSH
arguments a new dimensions: deterioration in skills due to severity of a demand
shock and productivity shock. It does not, however, contradict the TSSH and does
not invalidate the key arguments of the TSSH. As per effectiveness of monetary
or monetary-fiscal policies in combatting the long-term nature of the adverse
economic equilibrium, the book remains open in my opinion, even under the
hysteresis hypothesis: if hysteresis is accompanied by a permanent loss of
skills twinned with a loss of productivity (e.g. due to technological
progress), adverse demographics (older age cohorts of workers losing their
jobs) will not be resolved by a training push. You simply cannot attain a catch
up for the displaced workers using training schemes in the presence of younger
generation of workers competing for the scarce jobs in a hysteresis
environment.
And the Zero-Lower Bound on monetary policy still matters: the duration of the
hysteresis shock will undoubtedly create large scale mismatch between the
sovereign capacity to fund future liabilities (deficits) and the longer-run
inflationary dynamics implied by the extremely aggressive and prolonged
monetary intervention. In other words, large enough hysteresis shock will
require Japanification of the economy, and as we have seen in the case of
Japan, such a scenario does not lead to the economy escaping the TSSH or
hysteresis (or both) trap even after two decades of aggressive monetary and
fiscal stimuli.