If
we think about the indifference curves in a slightly different way, we see that
MRS describes marginal benefit. Since MRS represents the maximum amount of y we
are willing to give up in exchange for one unit of x, it also represents how
much value our consumer places on x in terms of y.
This means the indifference curve
tells us the marginal benefit of good x in terms of good y, and the budget
line tells us the marginal cost of good x in terms of good y. As discussed
in Topic 1, using marginal analysis, our consumer will continue to purchase
more of a good until the marginal benefit is equal to the marginal cost. This
means
if MRS > Px/Py, the
consumer will consume more x and less y.
If MRS < Px/Py, the
consumer will consume less x and more y.
If MRS = Px/Py, the
consumer will not change their consumption.
Recall that MRS is the slope of
the indifference curve, and Px/Py is the slope of the budget line.
This means that if the slope of the indifference curve is steeper than that of
the budget line, the consumer will consume more x and less y.
Figure 6.3a shows José’s
budget line and possible indifference curves. As Point A, MRS is greater
than Px/Py, so José should consume more x and less y to maximize his
utility.
Moving along the
budget line (shown in black), we see this action indeed allows José to
consume on a higher indifference curve. At point B, MRS = Px/Py, so this
is the utility maximizing point, given José’s constraints. Notice that
since Point A and Point B are on the same budget line, José could increase
utility without a change in expenditures.
In summary, the consumer will consume at the point where the
indifference curve and the budget line are tangent, meaning the
slopes are equal.
We now have all the pieces to develop our model for consumer
theory. In Topic 3, we examined the law of demand, which showed that as the
price increased our quantity demanded of the good decreased. Now, let’s look at
how our consumption choices react to a change in price based on our
indifference curve and budget line.
Consider
a market with 100 consumers like José, each with budgets of $56 and
preferences as illustrated in Figure 6.3b.
The graph shows the final effect
of a price increase on T-shirts. Suppose T-shirts have increased from $14
to $28.
The easiest way to graph a price
change is to assume José spends all of his money on T-shirts to see how the
intercept will change. Following the price increase, he can only purchase 2
T-shirts. ($56 budget / $28/T-shirt) Because we are imagining a market with 100
consumers like José, all in all, 200 T-shirts will be bought. The price
increase causes the budget line to pivot inwards and changes the price
ratio from Px/Py = 2 to Px/Py = 4.
Since we know the price of movies
has not changed, we know that José can still purchase 8 movies and can show the
new graph with our knowledge of these points.
In our example, this causes
consumers to change consumption from 200 T-Shirts and 400 Movies (Point A) to
around 70 T-Shirts and 500 Movies (Point C). Why is this the case? Can we tell
from this graph whether the two goods are compliments or substitutes? Normal or
inferior?
To answer these questions, we can
decompose the consumer’s response into two parts:
1.
The substitution effect (SE): isolates the effect of the
change in relative prices, by holding well-being constant.
-Draw a BL with the same slope as
the new one, but draw it touching the original IC at the point of tangency.
-The movement from the old optimal
consumption point to this new tangency point is the SE.
2.
The income effect (IE): isolates the effect of the change in
purchasing power (well-being), holding prices constant.
-Draw the final BL associated with
the price change.
-The movement from the consumption
point on the BL drawn in the SE to the optimal point on the final BL is the IE.